Are Roads and Highways Subsidized ?

by David S. Lawyer mailto:davylawyer1@gmail.com More articles by David Lawyer

March 2004, revised July 2007, Mar. 2008, June 2015
Discusses the question of subsidy of highway users by the general taxpayer. Shows that in the late 20th century it was not clear whether or not highways were actually being subsidized. In the early 20th century, they were heavily subsidized and today, in the 21st century, they are moderately subsidized. One purpose of this report is to explain to the public the various points of view and let the reader judge whether or not highways were actually subsidized during the last 100 years. However, the opinion of the author is that regarding the use of highways today, large trucks are subsidized while subsidy to autos ranged from about 0 to 15% from the mid 1920's until the early 21st century. As the 21st century advanced the subsidy to highways grew to 30% in 2010 and the future of subsidy is unclear.

1. Introduction

2. Overview of the History of Subsidy

3. How to Measure Subsidy?

4. Diversion of Highway User Revenues to Mass Transit, etc.

5. Subsidy for Some Years 1936-2005

6. Exaggerated Claims of High Subsidy to Highways

7. Estimating Subsidy from Table HF-10

8. Is Subsidy to Highways Always a Subsidy?

9. Allocation of Costs to Trucks

10. No Sales Tax Subsidy

11. Land Rent Subsidy?

12. Property Tax Subsidy

13. Conclusions

14. Appendix: Calculation of Subsidy Using Table HF-10

15. Appendix: Misinterpretation and Complications of Table HF-10

16. Bibliography of Highway Finance

17. Internet


1. Introduction

In the late 20th century, there was little (if any) subsidy to highways so I wrote: "Are the roads, streets and highways that we drive on in the United States subsidized by the government, or do the taxes on gasoline and license fees pay all (or most all) of the highway costs? And if highways (includes roads and streets) are subsidized, how much is the subsidy?" We are talking here about the costs of construction and maintaining highways, including highway patrols, etc. The highway costs are of course only part of the costs of highway transportation which also includes the following: the costs of purchasing and maintaining motor vehicles, costs of motor vehicle fuel (before taxes), costs of parking structures, etc.

While in the 1990's, highway users paid nearly 100% (and sometimes more) of the costs of highways, in the 21st century (after 2000) that 100% started to drop reaching a low of only 70% in 2010. See Subsidy Table. An alleged reason for this was the failure of politicians (influenced by voter sentiment) to increase gasoline taxes so that highways users would fully pay for the roads and highways they drive on.

If one searches the Internet for the answer to the question of highway subsidy, one finds a number of sites that claim that there is high subsidy for highways. The implication of this is that since highways are heavily subsidized, it's OK to also subsidize other modes of transportation such as mass transit and Amtrak. The fallacy of such reasoning is that one wrong doesn't justify another (or two wrongs don't make a right). If highways are subsidized and this subsidy is wrong, it doesn't justify subsidy to other modes of transportation which may also be wrong.

A couple of websites claim that there is little or no subsidy to highways but by 2015 both had failed to keep up-to-date and realize that in the 21st century subsidy has rapidly grown from about 0% in 1995 to about 30% in 2010. The first website is Are Highways Subsidized? by Randal O'Toole which uses the same method I used to estimate subsidy and obtains about the same results (for the same years). His article goes into the history of automobilisation of America and portrays the auto as bringing great social benefits at modest social cost. I don't fully agree, since the environmental costs were high and it resulted in land use that engendered excessive amounts of travel. But to pursue this here would be off topic. (See Travel less)

The second website, which apparently is not being kept up-to-date is US Highways & Streets: Revenues & Expenditures by Wendell Cox. I believe that Cox's analysis is a little biased and understates subsidy to highways. See Discrepancy in Wendell Cox's Table. However, the claims made by others that highways are heavily subsidized are even more erroneous (in the opposite direction).

This report will show that the situation has significantly changed in the past couple of decades so that today highways (on average) are definitely being subsidized. But if one goes back to the 20th century it was debatable. Also, it looks like there is significant subsidy to large trucks using the highways. As you will soon see, the situation is far from simple.

2. Overview of the History of Subsidy

2.1 Overview

The situation today, where highways are only moderately subsidized was not true for bygone years. Prior to the introduction of the gasoline tax by various states during the 1920's, highways were heavily subsidized by the general taxpayer. After that, the subsidy to roads was either low or non-existent until the early 20th century when there was more public opposition to raising gasoline taxes.

2.2 Before the Automobile:

Before the automobile in about 1900, the huge highway system of the United States, consisted of about 2 million miles of mostly dirt roads and was about 10 times the length of the railroad system. These roads were almost all 100% subsidized by the general taxpayer and by citizen labor supplied free of charge. Except that major bridges charged tolls to cross rivers.

Roads were often built and maintained by "poll labor". For example in the 1820's the state of Indiana required that all able-bodied men work 2 days on the roads each year (without pay). However, one could pay money to avoid such duty. The poll labor method of highway support was widely used throughout the world. Also, some road were built by the military and were made available for public use.

Starting with the Lancaster (Pennsylvania) Turnpike in 1794, a large number of toll roads were constructed (for use by animal powered transportation, including walking), but by 1860 they had mostly failed due in large part to competition from canals and railroads. The turnpike era from 1800 to 1830 saw the construction of many better quality unpaved toll roads known as "turnpikes". From 1845 to almost 1860 was the era of plank toll roads introduced from Russia. Vehicles rolled along on thick wood planks but the exposed wood soon deteriorated. Several thousand miles of toll roads were built. See Transportation Revolution and Transportation (by Bigham)

But even during the toll road era most of the roads were still free to use but in poor condition. The toll roads were 100% pay and often in good condition. But remember that due to the typical poor condition of the roads and the slow speeds (usually a few miles per hour or less) and low population, there was far less travel as compared to today.

2.3 The Coming of the Automobile

The last two decades of the 1800's saw the start of the "good roads" movement which was mostly due to support of farmers and bicyclists who wanted the government to pay for better roads. As a result, some states created highway departments which provided highway financial aid from the states. New Jersey was first in 1881 but it wasn't until 1917 that all state governments were aiding (subsidizing) highways. and Transportation (by Bigham) p.103

Highways at first (before gasoline taxes) were mostly financed by local taxes, especially property taxes. Thus the use of highways was almost 100% subsidized, but that started to change in 1910 when there were almost a half million automobiles in the U.S., and New York state started charging automobile registration fees. Soon all states had such fees and in 1919 (when there were almost 8 million autos) Oregon imposed taxes on gasoline to finance roads. By 1929, with 23 million autos, all states had such fuel taxes. See Locklin, 1947, p.670. In addition, in 1916, the federal government entered the picture with its "Federal Aid Road Act of 1916". Not to be outdone by the states, a federal tax on motor vehicle fuel was introduced in 1932.See Transportation (by Bigham) p.105 and Federal Motor Fuel Taxes But it wasn't until 1956 that the federal government started to levy a user-tax on gasoline that paid for highway constuction.

Prior to the 1920's there was no national network of paved highways, and the railroad remained the mainstay of long-distance land travel. Railroad traffic grew as improved local roads provided improved access to railroad stations for both passengers and freight. So in this way the subsidy to roads benefited railroads too. But as a national network of paved roads was created in the 1920's and 1930', the railroads lost traffic to trucks and long-distance auto trips.

Even after these user charges were in place, minor roads (such as residential streets) were still mostly paid for by local governments (city and county). However in the late 20th century, highway user charges started to be used for non-highway purposes, including the purposes of reducing the national debt and to support mass transit. In a couple of cases these diversions (a reverse subsidy of sorts) exceeded the subsidy from property taxes and other non-user money for local roads. This provided a rationale for some to claim that highways were no longer subsidized. Even when local streets are subsidized, one may argue that it's not really a subsidy Is Subsidy to Highways Always a Subsidy? and Allocation of Costs to Trucks.

With gasoline taxes being enacted by states in the 1920s, the Federal Coordinator of Transportation (in in 1930s) concluded that since 1927, highway users were no longer being subsidized. After that, until the start of the 21st century, subsidy was either low or non-existent but then due to the failure to increase gasoline taxes in the 21st century, taxes paid by highway users only constituted 70% of tax money used for highways in 2010 while in 1995 it had been 100% (no subsidy). See Net subsidy table

3. How to Measure Subsidy?

Highways are financed by user revenues (gasoline tax, vehicle registration fees, tolls) and by non-user taxes (property tax, sales tax, and income tax). Some of the money comes from surplus user revenues from years past, including interest earned on them. Today, more and more highway financing is being paid for by going into debt and issuing bonds. The situation is further complicated since about 20% of highway user revenues are being diverted for non-highway purposes such as mass transit. So how would one define user fees paid by highway users? Does it include the money paid for gasoline taxes, but diverted to non-highway uses such as mass transit? Or is this not really a diversion but an excise tax imposed on highway users for special purposes. This is discussed in detail in the next section. Another problem is debt financing. How much of this debt will be paid back by highway users and how much will be paid back by non-users?

4. Diversion of Highway User Revenues to Mass Transit, etc.

4.1 Introduction

One complication is that part of the money obtained from gasoline taxes at the fuel pump is spent for non-highway purposes. In 2005, about 19% of user revenues (including registration fees and tolls) were diverted for nonhighway purposes with over 45% of the amount diverted going to subsidize mass transit. This contributes to a shortfall in revenues needed for highways and it's made up for by using property taxes, general fund revenues, and other taxes to pay for highways. Should these non-user revenues (such as general funds) that are spent on highways count as being used for highways or are they indirectly flowing to mass transit and other non-highway uses since they are used for making up the shortfall due to diversion of highway user taxes to mass transit, etc.?

For 1995, the total amount of non-user revenues used for highways just happened to be about equal to the amount of user-revenues diverted for non-highway purposes (such as mass transit). Is there subsidy here? Well, there certainly is subsidy for mass-transit, etc. But are highways being subsidized? Highway user-revenues are certainly sufficient to pay for highway costs if they were used for that purpose, so one may claim that there isn't any subsidy to highways. But part of the money users pay flows to support non-highway purposes.

But for 2005 (unlike 1995) non-user revenues were about double that of the diversion thus implying at about a 13% subsidy to highways. Furthermore, its not exactly clear that this 13% is really a subsidy as is discussed later on in Is Subsidy to Highways Always a Subsidy? and Allocation of Costs to Trucks.

Why the big change from 1995 to 2005? In 1995, the federal government was diverting substantial amounts of gasoline taxes (4.3 cents per gallon) to reduce the national debt (deficit) but this ceased in 1997. See Addendum to the 1997 Federal Highway Cost Allocation Study Final Report.

This diversion in 1995 increased the total diversion to the point where it was about equal to the non-user revenues from property taxes, etc. collected that year. Repealing the diversion, enacted in 1993, resulted in positive net subsidy to highways, the normal case before this diversion started.

For summary statistics on which the above discussion is based, see "Funding for Highways and Disposition of Highway-User Revenues, All Units of Government", Table HF-10 in "Highway Statistics" (annual) by the Federal Highway Administration. See hints for finding Table HF-10 on the Internet.

If one neglects to consider the diversions from gasoline tax, etc., then one can look at table HF-10 for 1995 and claim that about 25% of revenues from taxes came from property taxes, general funds, and other taxes. While this is true, it's not really subsidy since it's equal to the amount diverted from user-revenues. We are asking the question: Do user-revenues (including revenues diverted) fully cover highway costs?

Another way to look at this is to consider the diversions from gasoline taxes as subsidy to mass transit, and subsidy to other non-highway purposes. In other words highway users are subsidizing non-highway projects but at the same time, general taxpayers (property, sales, and income taxes) are subsidizing highways. The question being asked is: what is the net subsidy to highways, which is equal to the subsidy to highways less the subsidy paid by highway users for non-highway purposes.

An example which illustrates why the real subsidy should be only the net subsidy is as follows. Suppose that all taxes on airline tickets were used to pay for highways and conversely: all highway user taxes were used to pay for the operation of the airways and airports. Furthermore, suppose that these costs were equal: the user tax for airline tickets is equal to the taxes paid on gasoline, tolls, etc. Then one might claim that the airways are 100% subsidized since highway users are paying for them. Likewise, one might claim that highways are 100% subsidized since air travelers are paying for them. But actually, the user charges for each mode are sufficient to pay all the costs for that mode and neither the airways nor the highways are being subsidized. Each system pays the other the same sum of money which is equivalent to no exchange of money at all. If I give you $1000 and you give me back $1000, it's like no exchange has taken place (we each have the same amount of money as before). Of course, the actual subsidy situation is much more complex.

4.2 Are Diverted Taxes Just Another Tax?

While I argue above that it's the net subsidy which counts, there is the opposite point of view described as follows: If one believes that the highway user should be subject to "sin taxes" like those leveled on tobacco and alcohol, then after paying the sin tax, there is still a tax to be paid to finance highway construction and maintenance. From this perspective, one should count the total subsidy to highways and not the net subsidy. Then claims of heavy subsidy to highways would be justified.

The key question here is: Is using the highways a sin? Is using highways hurting the environment? Well, yes, but lots of other activities are also hurting the environment but avoid sin taxes. Let's first look at energy efficiency of the various modes of transportation: Transportation Energy Data Book, Ch. 2. It turns out that the energy-intensity of the automobile is roughly equal to that of mass transit. So if using the highways is damaging the environment, so is using mass transit which is being subsidized by highway users and not paying any "sin taxes". Why aren't the "sin taxes" being levied on transit users as well? Furthermore, since most other activities such as heating and air-conditioning ones home, is consuming fuel and doing environmental damage, why are not sin taxes being levied on all energy consuming activities? Good question. Perhaps what we need are sin taxes on all fuels.

So it seems that levying sin taxes on just motor vehicle use of highways is unduly discriminatory. So thus the subsidy to highways should probably be the net subsidy.

It would make the analysis much simpler and clearer if all of the user revenues for highways were spent only on highways and the funds used for non-highway purposes were obtained from non-highway revenues. But that's not the way it's been set up by government.

5. Subsidy for Some Years 1936-2005

The following table shows how net subsidy to highways has dramatically increased in the 21st century (after 2000).


        NET SUBSIDY TO HIGHWAYS (in billions of dollars)
        (derived from FHWA Table HF-10) by David S. Lawyer
ITEM                               1995  2000  2005  2010  2012  
User Fees (gas taxes, etc.)        84.1 100.6 114.6 120.4 142.5
Non-user taxes (gross subsidy)     21.4  29.0  39.2  80.2  69.3
Less diverted to non-highway uses  21.6  16.6  21.4  24.7  26.2
Net subsidy (diff of above 2 lines) -.2  12.4  17.4  55.6  43.0
Total taxes used for highways      78.0 107.1 126.8 171.6 205.1
Net subsidy (% of "Total taxes...") -.3  11.6  14.0  32.4  21.0

The "net subsidy" in the above table is estimated per the author's method which from gross subsidy subtracts the reverse subsidy of non user taxes imposed on highway users (for mass transit etc.). This reverse subsidy represents revenues "diverted" to non-highway uses (such as mass transit), from fees imposed on highway users such as the fuel tax on gasoline.

Note that for 1990 (and earlier) the Table HF-10 doesn't exist. Table 88 90-11 (fix-me) (in "Highway Statistics" for 1990) is something like HF-10 but fails to show diversion of user revenue for other purposes.


        HIGHWAY COST ALLOCATION STUDY, 1961 
        (87th Congress, House Doc. No. 54)
                                 Motor Vehicle     Other Revenue
                                    Users            Sources
Interstate System                   94.6%              5.4%
Other primary federal-aid system    92.6%              7.4%
Secondary federal-aid system        71.6%             28.4%

Note that only main highways are in the federal-aid system. So local roads are excluded from the above which likely had a larger share of financing by "Other Revenue Sources".

Note that in 1936 local roads costs (of counties and towns) were about 1/3 of total highway costs and about 50% of such costs were paid for by user fees. See Johnson p.552. For the 2/3 spent on main highways, it's not clear how much is subsidy since "Federal aid and grants" is not partitioned into user fees from federal taxes on fuel and tires and federal grants from the general fund (some of which was supposedly to provide employment during the great depression).

6. Exaggerated Claims of High Subsidy to Highways

The many claims that highways are heavily subsidized are usually based on neglecting the diversions of highway user-revenue. In other words, they are looking at the total subsidy rather than the net subsidy. In one case (see NARP - Congressional Testimony it mentions the amount diverted for "Nonhighway Purposes" but neglects the amount diverted for mass transit which is listed separately in Table HF-10 but insidiously omitted from this testimony before congress.

Unfortunately, even government sites can be deceptive. The U.S.A. Census table only shows what's left of user fees after diversion of funds to non-highway purposes and titles it "Imposts on Highway Users". See Funding for Highways, by Level of Government statistics - USA Census numbers Of course, the amount diverted to transit, etc, is also a charge levied on highway users.

Only small footnote mentions that this "excludes amounts later allocated for nonhighway purposes". In another case, data from the HF-10 table was used to create a smaller table with no mention of diversion of funds, but the amount of "highway user revenues" is shown net of the diversion to nonhighway uses with no mention of this fact on the webpage. See FundingForHighways EW-Gateway

7. Estimating Subsidy from Table HF-10

7.1 Introduction

There are various ways to estimate subsidy from Table HF-10 and possibly other data. The question of net vs total subsidy has already been covered.

7.2 Method: Gross subsidy less diversion

At present, I think the most reasonable method is to just find the net subsidy: subtract the diversions to non-highway purposes (including mass-transportation) from the gross subsidy by non-user taxation. For details see Appendix: Calculation of Subsidy Using Table HF-10

7.3 Method: Percent of expenditures from user charges

One might alternatively ask the question: What percent of money spent on highways this year came from user charges. This method is a good one as stated but impractical to use since for debt financing, it's not known what portion of the debt will actually paid back by the highway users . However, it's possible to obtain erroneous results by simply neglecting debt financing in the calculations. This is the method used in a study sponsored by the Transportation Research BoardSee table 2-3.

To give a simple example of a flaw in this method, assume for the moment that there are no diversions of user fees to non-highway uses (such as mass transit). If only 50% of highway yearly expenses come from highway user fees collected during a year, does this imply that half of highway cost are being subsidized by non-highway users (such as by income taxes, property taxes, etc)? Of course not! This 50% of the highway expenditure that users don't pay could be raised by selling bonds (by borrowing and going into debt). If the highway users will pay back this debt (plus interest) in the future (via highway user fees) then in the long run there is no subsidy. Highway users just postpone 50% of their payment for use of the roads and highways and pay the bill for them later on.

Another reason it's flawed is similar. It's because some highway expenses are financed by investment income and draw-down of reserves obtained in past years when user revenues were higher than expenses and the resulting surplus was invested and put into reserves. This money is not subsidy although when this money is spent it is accounted for as expenditures not finances by uses and thus presumably subsidy. If highway users contributed to creating these funds in the past, spending them (plus interest) today is user revenue but it's not counted as such.

The form HF-10 counts investment income as income but is it really? In today's (2015) economy it's mostly not really income since it mostly serves to maintain the real value of the investment (if the interest rate is roughly equal to the inflation rate). Thus investment income can be treated to some degree just like an increase in the numerical amount in reserves but not as any significant increase in the real value of the reserves.

8. Is Subsidy to Highways Always a Subsidy?

Is what has been called subsidy to highways above always a subsidy? There is no definite answer to this question. Local streets and access roads have traditionally been paid for by local non-user taxes long before automobiles existed. One justification for paying for local roads by property taxes is alleged to be that land is of almost no utility unless there is access to it and that local roads are required for such access. This is the case for access both to city residences and rural residences where one needs to drive to town to purchase food and supplies. It also includes farm-to-market roads and the like.

Even though one doesn't use an automobile, access is still needed to maintain the property (deliver heavy furniture and appliances etc.) and also to supply building materials to construct buildings on the property. For rural residents, "access" may include the route taken to get to a nearby town to purchase supplies (including farm supplies). See Locklin, pp.672-3 which, while supporting the concept of property tax financing, also points out the advantages of financing by highway users rather than by property taxes. In 2012 per HF-10, the contribution to highway costs by gereral fund revenues was over 4 times the amount supplied by property taxes and was only about 5% of the total taxes used for highway support.

However, there are arguments as to why not only property tax but some general fund revenues are not subsidy. One argument is that everyone must live somewhere and thus everyone needs access to property and thus it's not subsidy to make them pay some taxes for it. However today (in 2015) about 20% of highway "disbursements" (expenses) comes from gereral funds and some of this likely represents subsidy by those who don't depend much on highways.

An FHA report (see "Final Report of the Federal Highway Cost Allocation Study", U.S. DOT, FHA, 1982. p.I-5 and Appendix F) estimates that if non-user taxes are to pay for access costs, they should pay nearly 39% of road costs while they actually only paid about 25%. While this 39% estimate seems to the author to be unreasonably high, if one accepts this estimates, then the subsidy for road cost is flowing in the reverse direction: from the motorist to the non-user. The same report estimates that even if road users are assigned such access road cost, the non-users should still pay about 7% of road costs due to their benefits obtained from such items as street lighting, sidewalks, storm drains, etc.

Another point of view would argue as follows: Users of local residential streets (or local roads with low traffic) should be charged full user charges but since the gasoline tax is insufficient to cover these costs (due to low usage of such roads) the shortfall should be made up for by property taxes. Thus property tax revenues are supposedly only a temporary expedient until the practical technology is developed to charge motorists differential user charges (on different roads). On low traffic roads (such as in residential neighborhoods) motorists would then need to pay higher usage fees.

9. Allocation of Costs to Trucks

Another problem is that of separation of automobile and truck costs for their use of highways. It is often claimed that heavy trucks do the lion's share of damage to highways and are in part subsidized by automobiles. How much this amounts to is a debatable point, but even more difficult is the problem of allocating "residual" road costs between autos and trucks. "Residual" costs are the costs which the auto and truck share and are not attributable to the truck alone (for example the costs of excavation of earth when building the road, the costs for the thickness of pavement needed to only support automobiles, etc.). In economics, this is called "joint costs".

The method used for allocating these so called "residual" costs by the above mentioned FHA Cost Allocation Study is to charge the same for an auto-mile as for a truck-mile. This is likely biased in favor of trucks since a truck-mi would be expected to usually provide more utility than an auto-mile. This biased study then reports that only roughly 10% of auto user charges go to pay for road costs due to trucks (see p.I-13) but for an unbiased study the actual amount would be higher.

Results from a more recent study are summarized in Federal Highway Cost Allocation Study - Public Roads, January/February 1998 and a now dead url" "http://www.battelle.org/news/98/39highway.stm" named "Battelle Press Release: Highway Costs">. 2000 Addendum to the 1997 Federal Highway Cost Allocation Study Final Report The Addendum modified the results of the study and claims that combination trucks (the ones where a "tractor" pulls one, two, or three trailers behind it) only pay 80% of their allocated costs (with ones over 40 tons paying only 50% of allocated cost). The heavier (and larger) the truck, the greater the subsidy. Autos pay 100% of their costs while pickup trucks and vans pay 150% of their cost. Thus it appears that heavy trucks are being subsidized by the motorist and by smaller trucks.

The addendum shows makes it clear that the government considered the highway user fees diverted to the general fund for the purpose of deficit reduction to not be user charges. Thus when Congress stopped this diversion and the fees collected went to support highway costs, they considered that user fees from fuel had increased, resulting in combination trucks only paying 80% of their allocated costs instead of the previous 90%. But there really wasn't any change in user fees since motorists were still paying the same taxes on fuel and the subsidy to trucks really hadn't actually changed (if one considers the deficit-reduction tax a user fee -- this study didn't but the author of this report does).

The reason why pickups and vans pay more than their fair share is mainly due to the fact that they get worse miles per gallon and thus wind up paying more fuel taxes. This study assumes that such vehicles cost no more for highway costs than automobiles even though they weigh more and thus do slightly more damage to the pavement. But since heavy trucks are responsible for the lion's share of such damage the small additional damage done by pickups and vans is neglected. Thus all personal transportation vehicles that are "gas guzzlers" are paying significantly more than their fair share of highway costs and are subsidizing heavy trucks.

10. No Sales Tax Subsidy

In many states, no sales tax is levied on motor fuel (gasoline and diesel). Such a tax exemption results in a subsidy to motor fuel and hence a subsidy to automobiles and trucks. Even when a sales tax is imposed, some of the money may be diverted to highway uses instead of going to the general fund. What justification is there for fuels to be exempt from sales taxes? Well, natural gas and fuels used to generate electricity aren't subject to sales taxes either (but perhaps they should be).

This failure-to-sales-tax-gasoline subsidy is large since fuel prices are high. The amount of sales taxes not paid would be perhaps roughly half of the amount of user taxes on fuel. But while this is a subsidy to motor vehicles, is it a subsidy to highways? Probably not, but it reveals a possible subsidy to highways explained next.

Recall that to find the net subsidy, we subtracted the amount of diversion of gasoline taxes, etc. for non-highway purposes. It turns out that a small part the money diverted is put into the general fund, just like sales tax revenue would be. Thus it could be considered as money diverted in lieu of sales taxes since its effect is just like a sales tax. Thus it would be viewed, not be a subsidy paid by motor vehicles for other purposes, but as a legitimate sales tax on fuel, which should not be deducted from gross subsidy. Even some of the money diverted to mass transit might be viewed in this way: it's like a special sales tax to finance mass transportation.

Just how much of the diversion is put into the general funds by the states? It's either a lot or a little depending on whether you look at gross or net. For 2005 (per "Highway Statistics" table DF) out of 63.54 billion of state user revenues, 2.11 billion (a lot) was put into the general funds. But as the same time, 1.85 billion was withdrawn from the general funds to finance highways. Subtracting this leaves only a net of 0.36 billion (a little) diverted from highway users into the general fund.

It's interesting that for some states, a large amount is diverted to the general fund while at the same time exactly the same amount is withdrawn from the general fund to support highways. The result is "no result" except for transactions on the books that cancel each other out. Why? It may be that the general fund is just a convenient fund to use for passing user fees thru to highway expenditures. It also allows flexibility in case the deposits from highway users and withdrawals for highway expenses become unequal it the future. But it also provides the opportunity for those who ignore diversions of highway user fees to claim that highways are subsidized from the general fund more than they actually are.

11. Land Rent Subsidy?

It's sometimes claimed that highway users should pay rent for the land on which the highways rest. If one takes the point of view that it's the highway users who own this land collectively, then they shouldn't need to pay rent for land that they already own. When the government builds highways, they often need to buy the land for the highway and the money to pay for this land comes mostly from highway users. For local streets, land for subdivisions (including land for streets) is purchased by developers and the cost of such land is included in the price of homes or lots. If the land was originally public land then one can alleged that the public land was given to highway users. So from this perspective, highway users have already paid for (or been otherwise granted) the highway land and shouldn't need to pay rent on it.

But in actual fact, the government owns the highway land, much of which was paid for by highway users. Should it charge rent for the use of such land? Public parks and forests generally don't charge any land rent to use them, although user fees are often imposed to pay for maintenance of them. But parks are a little different than highways since almost everyone can use parks while only people who own highway vehicles (such as autos, bicycles, etc.) can use highways.

From another perspective, land rents may represent unearned income and are immoral. Land was not created by people and thus land rent shouldn't be charged for its use, at least not by the government. One may claim that this is a Marxist argument, but its validity should not be judged by associating it with Marxism. From this perspective, the government has no business charging land rents.

So how much (if any) highways are being subsidized by failure to charge land rent for their use is an open question.

12. Property Tax Subsidy

Even if one assumes that highway users own the highway system, the question remains as to why they are not paying property taxes on the highways. Does the lack of property taxes on highways represent a hidden subsidy to highways? One may claim that the value of access to property by streets and roads is incorporated in the price (and value) of taxable real property. For example, your home is more valuable since there is a street in front of it used to get to your home. Since property taxes are being paid on such property, then one may allege that part these taxes represent taxes on streets and roads that serve such property.

However, when private railroads were competing with highways for passengers, it seems to be inequitable that property taxes were being levied on railroad track but none on the highways. For freight, this inequitable situation persists to the present day. However, since freight railroads are inherently monopolies that are not well regulated today, it's not clear that reducing taxes on them will be of public benefit.

13. Conclusions

Frequent and mostly erroneous claims were made in the 20th and 21st century of high subsidy of roads and highways by the general taxpayer although prior to the mid-1920s (before gasoline taxes existed) such claims would have been true. In the 21st century, highway subsidy reached up to 30% (moderate subsidy) in 2010, due mostly to the failure of politicians to increase the gasoline tax. Claims of high subsidy to highways tend to be biased due to their neglect of the diversion of highway user charges for non-highway uses (such as mass transit) as well as failure to consider the benefits of streets to property owners. The purpose of much such biased reporting seems to be to justify high subsidy to public transportation.

All this doesn't mean that highways are good for the environment or that it was right to build them all and drive so much on them. Highways and the motor vehicles that run on them have very negatively impacted our environment, accelerated global warming, and due to importing of oil (and perhaps autos) contributed to huge foreign trade deficits for the U.S. But the fact remains that from the mid-1920's until the 21st century, highways were for the most part built and maintained by fees imposed on their users and partially imposed on property owners who benefited from them.

14. Appendix: Calculation of Subsidy Using Table HF-10

Here are the details of one way to calculate the subsidy of highways using Table HF-10. The table appears in the annual publication "Highway Statistics" by the Federal Highway Administration (part of the U.S. Dept. of Transportation). Table HF-10 is titled: "Funding for Highways and Disposition of Highway-User Revenues, All Units of Government". It includes data (and some estimates) from federal, state, and local governments.

The method is to first find the "gross subsidy" which is the highway revenue from non-user charges such as property taxes, income taxes, etc. Then the amount of money diverted from highway revenue by mass transit and other non-highway purposes is found. Subtracting this diversion from the "gross subsidy" gives the net amount of net subsidy:
Net_subsidy = Gross_subsidy - Diversion

The amount of gross subsidy is the same as the "Subtotal" for "Other Taxes and Fees" shown near the middle of the table. This "Other Taxes and Fees" subtotal is the sum of 3 items in the table: 1. "Property Taxes and Assessments", 2."General Fund Appropriations", 3. "Other Taxes and Fees" (not otherwise itemized above).

The amount of diversion is found by adding three items from near the top of the table: 1. "Less: Amount for Nonhighway Purposes", 2. "Less: Amount for Mass Transportation", 3. "Less: Amount for Territories". The "Amount for Territories" is subsidy for transportation in U.S. territories (smalls islands such as American Samoa). Note that the "Amount for Nonhighway Purposes" mentioned above does not include the "Amount for Mass Transportation" since both amounts are subtracted in the HF-10 table from "Receipts Available for Distribution" to obtain "Net Used for Highway Purposes". Other items are also subtracted in HF-10 such as "Less: Amount for Collection Expenses" but this is not a diversion but is an expense chargeable to highways since it's a cost for collecting taxes for highways.

One might object to allocating all the collection expense to highways since some of what's collected is used for non-highway purposes such as mass transit. However, this oversight is approximately compensated for by neglecting to charge highways with the collection cost of non-highway revenues diverted to finance highways such as the cost of collecting property taxes.

The "Net subsidy" in the above table is also reported as a percent of "Total taxes used for highways" which has excluded collection costs in order to make it more comparable to the use of property taxes and general funds to support highways since these amounts are likely net of collection costs. To obtain the "Total taxes ..." one adds together the HF-10: "Receipts Available for Distribution" (under the superheading "Disposition of Highway-User Revenue by Collecting Agencies") and the "Subtotal" of "Other Taxes and Fees" Then one subtracts the HF-10: "Less Amount for Collection Expenses" to obtain the result: "Total taxes ..."

15. Appendix: Misinterpretation and Complications of Table HF-10

The table HF-10 is not self explanatory unless it's closely examined and thought over. It's easy to make mistakes in using it. You should be looking over a copy of an HF-10 while reading this. This table is partitioned into 3 sub-tables, and one must read the heading of each such sub-table in order to understand HF-10. Each of these sub-tables is further partitioned by the use of titled boxes, each of which contains one or more line-items such as "Less Amount for Mass Transportation". For boxes with only one line-item, there is no separate title so the line-item names serve as the title.

For example, in the 1995 edition of HF-10 under the box title "Highway User Revenues" it shows the subtotal of such revenue to be only 60% of "Total Disbursements". A naive persons might think that this means that only 60% of highway costs are financed by users so the remaining 40% must therefore be subsidized and financed by non-highway revenues. But that's grossly wrong. The first error is that "Highway User Revenues" actually means: that portion of highway user revenues which are used for highways and not diverted to some other use such as mass transit. One could infer this by reading the title of the subtable: "Revenues Used for Highways ..." The figure we want is on the line item labeled "Net Collections" (or in later editions "Receipts Available for Distribution") under a major heading: "Disposition of Highway-User Revenue by Collecting Agencies". If one checks this line they find the values of "highway user revenues" before diversion and notes that HF-10 shows them to be 91% of total disbursements. The 91% should have been more accurately defined as the percent of "Grand Total Disbursements" which includes "Bond Retirements".

Since for 1995 there was almost no subsidy, why isn't the 91% above equal to 100% to indicate that highway users paid 100% of the costs. One reason is the double counting of bond financing. The "Disbursements for Highways ..." section of HF-10 shows expenditures and capital outlays and highway maintenance, and some of this represent the proceeds from the sale of bonds. But another component in "Grand Total Disbursements" is "Bond Retirements". This is double counting since we have counted both the money obtained from the loan (in the form of a bond) and the money used to pay back the loan. It's like a person keeping track of their car expenses of getting a new car on credit. If they buy a new car for say $30,000 on credit, they enter into their records a $30,000 expenditure when they get the car. Then later when they pay off the $30,000 loan they enter a $30,000 expense to pay off the loan. Adding the two expenses results in $60,000 expense for the car which is obviously specious reasoning since it's double counting the costs for a $30,000 car. One can't say the HF-10 is wrong since in a sense each item of the double counting is actually a disbursement. However HF-10 would be in error if they called disbursements "expenses" and a user of the table should not jump to the conclusion that "disbursements" necessarily represent expenses.

There are other problems with HF-10 such as the footnotes being mis-labeled in the 2010-2012 editions.

Example for 1995 (in billions of $) using HF-10 (Revised Jan. 1997): Gross_subsidy = 21.4
Diversion = 21.6 = 15.8 (Non-Highway Purposes) + 5.6 (Mass Transportation) + 0.1 (for Territories)

Net_subsidy = 21.4 - 21.6 = -0.2 Billion $. This is pretty insignificant as compared to the 92.5 billion $ of "Grand Total Disbursements" for 1995. Thus for 1995 there was essentially no net subsidy for highways: the taxes from highways users was just about equal to the expenditures for highways.

15.1 Discrepancy in Wendell Cox's Table

Note: If you haven't already, you'll need to read the above starting at Appendix: Calculation of Subsidy Using Table HF-10 to understand this section. The above method I used is somewhat similar to the method used by Wendell Cox to determine subsidy. See his US Highways & Streets: Revenues & Expenditures. What I call the "net subsidy" he calls "BALANCING: Excess of Non-Highway Revenues over Expenditures". By "Expenditures" he means non-highway expenditures.

For 1995 the value he shows for the "Excess" is -2.9 billion but I got only got -0.2 billion. Why the discrepancy? It's simply because he erroneously includes "Collection Expenses" under his "NON HIGHWAY EXPENDITURES" in his table. This is wrong since the expense to collect taxes paid by highway users (gasoline tax, license plate fees, etc.) is a legitimate highway expenditure in cases where gross tax revenues have been reported as revenues. Checking the numbers, the discrepancy of his -2.9 minus my -0.2 is -2.7 billion while the collection expenses that he failed to exclude were 3.0 billion (close to the 2.7 discrepancy). But there is still a residual discrepancy of 0.3 (not entirely due to rounding) which is due to my using the Jan. 1997 revision of the 1995 table while Wendell Cox likely used another revision (or the original issue) with slightly different numbers.

This discrepancy of erroneously including "Collection Expense" in Cox's "NON-HIGHWAY EXPENDITURES" was made for all years reported in his table (not just for 1995). I emailed him years ago about this and got a short response (that as I recall neither seemed to admit nor deny the error) but it hasn't been fixed yet.

What amounts to the same error is in Cox's table section "REVENUES COMPARED TO EXPENDITURES" subsection "Revenues over Expenditures" by which he means highway user revenues over highway expenditures. These values are identical to the ones in his "BALANCING" section that are due to including collection expense in non-highway expenditures.

But the errors in "Revenues over Expenditures" is calculated by subtracting what Cox considers to be "HIGHWAY USER REVENUES" from his "HIGHWAY EXPENDITURES".

15.2 Table HF-10, etc. on the Internet

One can use a search engine to find HF-10 but you will also find sites that just mention HF-10 like the site you are now reading. Or you can go to Highway Statistics and click on the year you want. Then click on "Highway Finance" and then find HF-10 and click on it. The problem is that if you want older ones you may need to download much more than just this one table.

16. Bibliography of Highway Finance

17. Internet

17.1 Books (Most are old)